Close Menu
    Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram
    Return to Fordham Law School
    X (Twitter) Facebook LinkedIn Instagram RSS
    Fordham Law News
    • Home
    • Law School News
    • In the News
    • Fordham Lawyer
    • Insider
      • Announcements
      • Class Notes
      • In Memoriam
    • For the Media
      • Media Contacts
    • News by Topic
      • Business and Financial Law
      • Clinics
      • Intellectual Property and Information Law
      • International and Human Rights Law
      • Legal Ethics and Professional Practice
      • National Security
      • Public Interest and Service
    Return to Fordham Law School
    X (Twitter) Facebook LinkedIn Instagram RSS
    Fordham Law News
    You are at:Home»Business and Financial Law»Richard Squire’s Article Named a Top 10 Corporate Law Article of 2017
    Richard Squire

    Richard Squire’s Article Named a Top 10 Corporate Law Article of 2017

    0
    By on April 25, 2018 Awards, Business and Financial Law, Faculty, Fordham Law Forward, Law School News

    An article co-authored by Fordham Law Professor Richard Squire has been chosen as a top 10 corporate and securities law article of 2017 by the Corporate Practice Commentator. The article was selected by corporate and securities law professors, who reviewed over 565 competitive articles.

    In the article, “Principal Costs: A New Theory for Corporate Law and Governance,” which was published in the Columbia Law Review, Squire and Zohar Goshen (Columbia Law School) argue against mandatory, one-size-fits-all legal rules that aim to reduce agency costs by obliging corporations to give more control to shareholders. Goshen and Squire claim that, because business firms vary in the costs they accrue from mistakes and disloyal conduct, the optimal division of control, including the optimal degrees of shareholder and managerial empowerment, is firm-specific. Thus, according to Goshen and Squire, lawmakers should permit each firm to develop its own corporate governance structure.

    To support their claim, Goshen and Squire make an important distinction between agency costs, produced when managers exercise control, and principal costs, produced when investors exercise control. In shaping their argument, the authors employ what they call “principal-cost theory,” which posits that a firm’s optimal governance structure minimizes the sum of both agency and principal costs.

    To further illustrate their claim on the importance of both cost forms, Squire employed a metaphor likening firms’ needs for suitable governance structures to nearsighted and farsighted peoples’ needs for appropriate eyeglasses. If an eye specialist seeks to achieve optimal vision for each patient but believes that only nearsightedness is a problem and thus only designs eyeglasses tailored for nearsighted people, then only nearsighted people will benefit from the eyeglasses.

    Applying the metaphor to his and Goshen’s argument, Squire explained that those who advocate solely for the reduction of agency costs fail to address the differing needs of various firms.

    “The agency-cost fundamentalists think that agency costs are the only problem, so they want one-size-fits all rules,” said Squire. “We argue that principal costs and agency costs are both problems, and the degree they are problems depends on the particular firm. So we expect firms to select the structure that strikes the right tradeoff for them, and to have about the same economic performance.”

    Squire noted how some critics of the article have claimed that he and Goshen have wrapped old ideas in new terminology. In response, Squire notes that prior literature fails to recognize principal costs as an important, distinct category, equal in relevance in corporate governance to agency costs.

    Furthermore and perhaps above all, the article gives theoretical and linguistic ammunition to people who resist proposed legal restrictions employed for greater shareholder empowerment. Through a careful articulation of their ideas, the two authors grant people a new model and lexicon with which to argue against a one-size-fits-all model.

    “The people who want to resist those laws now have a paper to reference and a theory to cite,” said Squire. “We have given the people who want a more hands-off approach to corporate law a framework from which to present about their concerns.”

     

     

    Increasing Our Scholarly Impact is one of the six objectives of the Law School’s strategic plan, Fordham Law Forward.

    Share. Facebook Twitter Pinterest LinkedIn Tumblr Email

    Related Posts

    Fighting for Military Justice: Meet Roxanne Roman ’26

    The Big Idea: Who Counts (and Who Doesn’t) in the U.S. Census 

    Helping Immigrant Families: Meet Christian Veliz ’28

    Comments are closed.

    • The Big Idea
    August 5, 2025

    The Big Idea: Who Counts (and Who Doesn’t) in the U.S. Census 

    March 31, 2025

    The Big Idea: Local Politics, Reform Prosecutors, and Reshaping Mass Incarceration

    March 3, 2025

    The Big Idea: Forced Labor, Global Supply Chains, and Workers’ Rights

    November 6, 2024

    The Big Idea: Partisanship, Perception, and Prosecutorial Power

    READ MORE

    About

    Fordham University - The Jesuit University of New York

    Founded in 1841, Fordham is the Jesuit University of New York, offering exceptional education distinguished by the Jesuit tradition to more than 15,100 students in its four undergraduate colleges and its six graduate and professional schools.
    Connect With Fordham
    © 2025 ThemeSphere. Designed by ThemeSphere.

    Type above and press Enter to search. Press Esc to cancel.